Paper on Contract Labour and Bondage in Andhra Pradesh (India)1
Wendy
K. Olsen, PhD
Lecturer in Quantitative Development Economics, Graduate School
University of Bradford, UK
and
R.V.
Ramana Murthy, PhD
Assistant Professor
NALSAR University of Law
Hyderabad, India
Year | Net Sown Area | Area Under Canals | Area Under Tanks | Net Irrigated Area |
1961 | 936,300 | 10,535 | 21,955 | 110,064 |
1971 | 1,053,713 | 22,430 | 25,730 | 108,753 |
1981 | 919,707 | 24,090 | 50,942 | 126,522 |
Mobilising forced labour for public works such highways, railway tracks, irrigation projects, etc., had been a common colonial practice (Kerr, 1998). Evidence suggests similar recruitments of labour originated in Mahabubnagar district. For instance, since 1934 labour groups were used to build the Nizamsagar dam by the Nizam government.8
The
introduction of large-scale irrigation in the post-independence period turned
this region into a source of cheap labour with a remarkable network of
middlemen. Such a relentless form exploitation in the region, has received
surprisingly little attention in the literature on labour. Walker and Ryan
(1990), writing about several well-funded
long-term village studies of which one was based in a palamuur labour
village, say very little about it. Nor do any official statistics exist to
capture the extent of it, as the Indian Census and National Sample Survey have
ignored seasonal migration. However, several researchers have noted a
significant level of presence of seasonally bonded labour in at least eight out
of twenty-four mandils of the District (Ravinder,
1989; Ramana Murthy, 1991; Reddy,
1990; Rao, Usha, 1994). The migrants from
Mahabubnagar district can be classified into three groups: firstly, those who
migrate for seasonal agriculture work in cotton, paddy and sugarcane growing
areas; secondly, those who migrate to Hyderabad and other cities to work in the
construction industry, usually also seasonally; and thirdly, those who migrate
on contract work. See for details Ramana Murthy (1991) and Usha Rao
(1994). In Mahabubnagar District alone local experts estimate that at
least 150,000 people go away to migration works every year. Of these,
about 50,000 (one third) are thought to be bonded labourers.
How the Palamuuru contract system works. There are two ranks of middlemen: group maistries (labour contractors) and maistries (supervisors). (We use the gender-specific term middlemen, although it is possible to have women taking on this role.9 All the intermediaries in this particular study area in 1991 and 1994 were male.) Construction companies place an order for the requisite labour force and advance a mutually agreed amount of money. Each group maistry patronises a team of maistries, each of whom actually mobilises a group of 20 to 30 labourers. The company forwards some money to the group maistry, who in turn passes some on to the maistry, after retaining his commission. The usual terms of the contract in both 1991 and 1994 were 8 to 9 months’ work, 12 hours work each day, a holiday for a fortnight, a pack of cheap cigarettes (beedies) for a man every week, and hair oil and food for the labourer and his/her dependent children. The advance was Rs. 2000 per worker in 1991 for an eight month contract for a man or a woman. Nominally, this was thought of as a monthly wage of Rs. 200 and provision of free food at the work site. Two days’ wages are deducted for a day's absence (one for the day's wage and the other for the free food). If a worker cannot work continuously, and falls sick, any medical expenses are deducted from the wage and counted as debt. Workers renew their contracts yearly, sometimes because they cannot redeem their loans and sometimes in order to obtain further loans. For labourers coming from landless and small peasant households struggling to subsist, the maistries are practically monopoly creditors and monopsony buyers of their labour power in the absence of alternative sources of credit and employment. Such contract labourers hail from the lower castes, enabling the middlemen to command enormous control in enforcing the contract, restricting their mobility at labour camps, and so on. The maistries have to guard the labourers to keep them from going away as their money is locked up in the investment. Accounts are settled with the higher-up contractors only at the end of the period. The respondents in the field study reported that many of the women suffer sexual exploitation, and that children are used for numerous unpaid services.
The construction companies in this way save a phenomenal amount of money, by paying much less than market wages on the one hand, and extracting four to six hours overtime without pay on the other.10 For example, simple calculations reveal that each labourer otherwise entitled to more than Rs. 10,000 for eight months work is given only Rs. 2000, the remaining being shared by the company and the middlemen.11 A maistry takes a gross commission of Rs. 30,000 and a group maistry Rs. 100,000 for one contract.12 As these middlemen invest money initially and settle accounts with the company only at the end of the year, they are highly exploitative. The company has no formal or written relation with the labourers. It is the maistry's responsibility to supervise, to extract work, and to settle the accounts as well as to settle disputes. Almost all the labourers are illiterate and rely totally on the maistry in settling accounts (Ramana Murthy, 1991).
The Palamuuru contract system violates the legal rights of workers. It contravenes the Bonded Labour Abolition Act 1976, the Interstate Migrant Workmen Act (Regulation of Employment and Conditions of Service) 1979 and the Minimum Wages Act 1974 of the Government of India.13 Consider for instance the case of Chenayya, 28 years old, of Palem village:
Field observations. We present the observations made during the field investigations (as part of a study on rural migration in the region) in August 1991 in five villages in three revenue divisions (mandals) and during another visit in October 1994 in these villages and one more village. The information presented here pertains to 49 contract labour households, which had in total 162 migrants. Some of these households were re-visited in October 1994. Information was elicited from the respondents using both questionnaires and informal inquiries. Four out of the six villages have exclusively contract labour migration, and two villages have casual labour migration as well. Inquiries were made about the socioeconomic background of the migrant labourers, the terms of their contracts, and why they went. We present a summary of these and some profiles of labourers before moving to the analysis section.
The villages were essentially poorly irrigated, semi-arid areas with red spongy soils having a low water retention capacity. Village tanks are the principal source of irrigation, supported by wells, irrigating less than one third of cultivated land (see Table 3). The main crops grown are paddy, jowar (sorghum), bajra (millet), groundnut and castor bean, as well as other pulses. Low irrigation in the villages limits commercial agriculture to those households with good soil and/or water supply.
Village | Area (Hectares) | Percent of Land Cultivated | Percent of Land Cultivable Waste | Percent Forest Land | Percent Irrigated by Any Source |
K. Nagula | 1989 | 55% | 1% | 10% | 9% |
Banala | 925 | 78 | 17 | 22 | 11 |
Balmur | 2160 | 58 | 1 | 1 | 17 |
Palem | 769 | 84 | 3 | 0 | 30 |
Pangal* | 2319 | 44 | 2 | 17 | 13 |
Mohammed Pur* | 836 | 80 | 0 | 0 | 7 |
* Note: These two villages have casual out-migration, whereas the others have exclusively Palamuuru contract out-migration on a seasonal basis.
Six out of the 162 contract labourers were aged above 45 years, and these reported 25 years of contract labour. These people had worked on the Bhakranangal dam (circa 1951), Hirakud (circa 1959), Nagarjunasagar dam (circa 1961), and various steel plants, railway lines, and road constructions since then (Ramana Murthy, 1991). Fifty-nine labourers between 35-45 years of age had been working since they were teenagers. Fifty-eight people aged between 25-35 and 37 people aged between 10-15 years were working in the ongoing Narmada Dam (Madhya Pradesh)-Sardar Sarovar (Gujarat) project funded by the World Bank. The health of the migrant workers deteriorates during the contract work, and many became unfit for this work by the age of 45 years.
Contract labourers primarily hail from landless agricultural labour households (22 percent) and marginal and small farm households (67 percent), as shown in Table 4. We have classified households owning less than 0.5 hectare of land as marginal; 0.5 to 2 hectares as small farms; and 2-4 hectares as semi-middle farms. With the recent distribution of waste land to landless households, the number of marginal households has risen. The caste-wise background of households having contract labourers showed 40 percent belonging to the scheduled castes, 15 percent to the scheduled tribes, and 45 percent to the backward castes. One household belonged to a so-called ‘forward’ caste.
Type of House-hold | Number of Households in Sample | Number of Contract Migrants | Age Distribution of Migrants | Gender | ||
10 to 15 Yrs | >15 Years | Male | Female | |||
I. Landless | 11 | 35 | 5 | 30 | 17 | 18 |
II. Marginal Farms | 19 | 58 | 17 | 41 | 26 | 24 |
III. Small Farms | 14 | 52 | 19 | 33 | 37 | 14 |
IV. Semi-Middle Farms | 5 | 17 | 1 | 16 | 14 | 2 |
Total: | 49 | 162 | 42 | 120 | 94 | 58 |
The gross farm incomes from the subsistence agriculture of these households were estimated in per capita terms to be Rs. 332; Rs. 1866; and Rs. 3970 in 1991 for the marginal, small and semi-middle farms respectively (Table 5). When the imputed costs of family labour were deducted, some households were shown to have negative net income.15 Needless to say, most of these people live below the official poverty line.
Type of Household | Average Land Holding (Acres) | Average Gross Farm Income | Per Capita Gross Income, Rupees, including Wages | Average Household Debt |
I. Landless | 0 | 0 | 1195 | 3831 |
II. Marginal Farms | 1.5 | 332 | 1575 | 3256 |
III. Small Farms | 4.1 | 1586 | 1450 | 3839 |
IV. Semi-Middle Farms | 9.1 | 3970 | 1206 | 6482 |
Note: Per capita gross income per annum was estimated as wage income in the case of landless labour and wages plus farm income in the case of the land-owning households. No income was imputed for own-labour on farms in the latter cases.
Type of Household | Indebtedness By Source of Loans (Percent Owing): | |||
. . . to the Maistry | . . . to the Moneylender | . . . to the Bank | . . . to Relatives and Friends | |
I. Landless | 56 | 32 | 0 | 12 |
II. Marginal Farms | 48 | 21 | 16 | 15 |
III. Small Farms | 32 | 31 | 21 | 16 |
IV. Semi-Middle Farms | 39 | 21 | 28 | 12 |
Note: The various debts of households were aggregated and divided by the number of households to arrive at average household debt of different farm size classes.
Instability and change in migration pattern.
There is a considerable instability in migration patterns seen during our
visits. In two villages, people were migrating as casual labour to
Hyderabad city, yet in these villages the Palamuuru contract system had
been prevalent. The transition to casual labour migration has been
encouraged by several factors. These villages had better irrigation
facilities, compared to the four contract-labour villages, and even compared
with the surrounding villages. The people’s personal knowledge of
Hyderabad city since the early 1980s had enabled them to wriggle out of the grip
of the contract system and the middlemen. However, this has only solved
the immediate subsistence problem inasmuch as they continue to sojourn between
their village and the city. They did not avail themselves of any
provisions in the city, such as ration cards or education of children.
With their incomplete integration into the urban economy and a faint hope of
improvement in the condition of the home village, they shuttled back and forth
between rural poverty and urban poverty.
As expressed by the migrants, the labour relations gain
acceptability for the reasons akin to those for accepting attached labour.
Oppression through reducing bargaining power:
i) Dyadic: the maistries have a grip if there is an outstanding loan. The debts incurred by migrant family members restrict their bargaining abilities in seeking either a contract or escape. Fixing workers into contract labour overtime restricts their access to information on labour markets elsewhere, further weakening their bargaining abilities.
ii) Structural: Many workers are so bankrupt and
destitute that they have few options other than working for the maistry.
However, those with some irrigated land and information on labour markets are in
a better position, and more of the casual labour migrants come from such
households (Ramana Murthy, 1991: 90-95). Workers who have relatives in
cities are also in a better position to bargain with potential employers, since
they can if necessary migrate to cities and look for work.
Oppression through the body (corporeal):
i) Dyadic: within a contract, the employer can control food intake, water supply, housing conditions, and to some extent the health care of the worker. Palamuuru labourers, debilitated by the relentless work, depend on their employer for further loans to maintain and improve their health. Occasional beatings and verbal abuse of those people who disobey the employer or who try to leave without repaying cause other workers to be self-disciplined labourers. There may be strong gender differences in the nature of corporeal oppression and these require further research.
ii) Structural: For many women the patriarchal system
denies them wages for domestic labour, and then lets their menfolk control the
wages they earn as employees. Women are expected to accept a lack of
personal spending money; domestic violence; and coercion from employers.
Sexual harassment of a woman who does physical outdoor work is seen by some
people as being the woman’s fault, since she shows herself in public.
The resulting embarassment or illicit sexual liaisons may be seen as oppressive
to women even though the people involved might think it perfectly acceptable.
In addition, female workers have to care for and feed children as well as
themselves while working (in fields or at construction sites). Men don’t
have this disadvantage, merely because they are men in a patriarchal society.
Most women’s mobility is more restricted than men’s, not only because of the
presence of children but also by the understanding that they are responsible for
the home/hut/tent and therefore do not have a right to leave it without
permission. These implicit constraints on women's mobility limit their
ability to secure information and improve their bargaining power. Norms
about the domestic roles of women cannot be neglected in considering their lives
as contract migrant workers.
Oppression through authority:
i) Dyadic: During the Palamuuru contract, as described above, the maistry has control over the movements and activities of the workers. Their control derives not only from the debt or contract, but also from class/caste identities and traditions of respect and servility that may operate between a maistry and a worker. In addition, a female worker may face the authority of her husband, brother, father, or mother-in-law who may force her to work and possibly also deprive her of control over her earnings. Children themselves are subject to authority of the elders, and in contract labour families, kids became contract labourers in their own right from the age of ten onwards (Ramana Murthy, 1991).
ii) Structural: Habits and traditions of inter-caste
behaviour may not require any explicit enforcement to remain extremely powerful.
Self-regulated submissive behaviour is embedded in the caste system, where
workers of lower castes do not eat food in front of an upper caste maistry,
may hesitate to touch them, keep a distance from them, do not enter their
home/hut or their cooking area, and so on. Employers hailing from the
upper castes may have high political, social and economic status.
Furthermore, when going in public the worker may face ridicule and ostracism if
they decide to flout the dictates of the maistry. The combination
of class and caste factors militates against the person’s consciousness in
fighting the employer. By contrast, workers who stay within the system
become a part of a cohesive group serving one maistry and are subject to
pressure to conform to the behaviour of that group.
Value exploitation:
i) Dyadic: It is possible to measure the gross profits reeled in by each maistry as the difference between their revenue and their wage bill to get a rough indicator of value-exploitation per worker and its variations. However this account will not cover the additional indirect exploitation undertaken by the construction company by underpayment and the overtime without pay. Handling the profits at local and higher levels requires more information and a clear conceptualisation of profit and surplus value. Firstly, input costs on the employer's side should be allowed for. Secondly, the profits realised by the contractor’s firm may increase over time after the contract itself is finished. A dyadic approach to estimating the rate of value-exploitation would suffer from the tendency to focus too heavily on direct relations of production (the labour relation) and to ignore indirect exploitation through exchange.
Nevertheless, even crude estimates, as given earlier, can have a powerful effect on consciousness since many workers may be unaware of the extent of exploitation. Another area ignored by the calculation of value exploitation between employer and employee is the extent of unpaid labour that is being done by women and children (and perhaps also men, if they go to collect firewood or to get water). In addition to cooking, watching children, cleaning, and doing other work aimed at reproduction of the labour force, women also provide sexual services (by choice or duress; for the husband or for the maistry). It was difficult to gather information on this important area without long periods of residence, but we have begun to develop an agenda for local research and activism.
ii) Structural: Perhaps more important than the pairwise rate of value-exploitation is the fact that these labourers seem to have a buffer between themselves and capitalist exploitation. They would have to fight off the maistries and group maistries before they could wage a class struggle with the ultimate employers or even find out who they are. The fight against parasitic middlemen would perhaps save them from bondage only to become free wage labourer in the usual capitalist sense (Miles, 1987). New forms of unfreedom may also emerge, as Brass contends, yet at least the current forms might disappear through the growing consciousness of the people. Such a radical consciousness is severely hindered by caste divisions and kinship loyalties (as Brass himself has pointed out, Brass (1986)).
The recognition of modes of exploitation in interlocked markets is useful in two ways – both for innovative research, as mentioned above, and for innovative strategies for action. The legal abolition of bonded labour has not succeeded in freeing bonded workers, though it may have had some effects on their consciousness. Twice in separate instances described by respondents, Palamuuru contract labour were declared as bonded labour and released—once by the Lathur District collector at the request of a local voluntary agency, and once more recently in Ranga Reddy District. There is no evidence of their rehabilitation. These people will, in all probability, have now re-entered contract work. One can argue for the formation of labour markets with generalised rights, yet continue the proletarian struggle for the reduction of value-exploitation and the elimination of oppression. One author has gone so far as to include among the definitional characteristics of ‘free wage labourers’ the proviso that they must have the genuine right to withdraw their labour through quitting or going on strike (Grossman, 1997). Grossman’s study, based in South Africa, illustrates how within capitalism the ‘freedom’ of workers is perpetually constrained. It also shows that ‘freedom’ is a social construct which can be used in many contexts to represent various situations as acceptable. At least one author has questioned the free/unfree dichotomy itself, arguing that it sets up a spectrum that lends itself to liberal and not to progressive values (Prakash, 1990). The debate over unfree labour is not a matter of ascertaining facts, but rather one of spreading an action-oriented awareness of exploitative social relationships.
One research proposal arising out of the rather
disturbing evidence above is to explore modes of resistance as well as modes of
oppression along the two dimensions shown in Table 1. In this way the
analysis presented in this paper moves beyond Hodgson’s original analysis and
moves toward the action orientation of most political economy authors.
However the model-making marxists, notably Bhaduri and Bardhan, have ignored the
need to analyse the change process and have instead
appeared to see the system as perpetually reproducing itself. Local
non-governmental organisations (NGOs) are working on watershed development and
natural resource management, and since the early 1990s they have begun to
involve members in micro-credit groups. However most of the NGO networks
have weak links at the grass roots at present. They could focus not only
on income-generation and substitute credit sources, but also on the cultural,
patriarchal, class, and caste bases of oppression in this region. The case
study suggests that strategies of the NGOs could perhaps be expanded to include
a wide range of anti-oppressive activities. Access to seaonal migrants
would have to be focused during the farming season, or else visits to the works
sites would be needed.
Interlocking of markets has received attention elsewhere in the literature. It has been argued that landlords’ interlinkages can reduce the accumulation of capital on the part of producers, leading to retarded growth (Bhaduri, 1973, 1983). The intermediaries in the Palamuuru labour case display a reactionary character by fixing a contract wage less than subsistence level, trapping the labourer in debt bondage. However we cannot say that this form of bondage is restricting the development of capitalism, when the labourers are creating infrastructure which can be seen as future means of production (e.g. roads; dams both for power and for irrigation). The rate of exploitation, direct and indirect, is high since intermediaries pay a wage much lower than urban market wages and extract considerable unpaid overtime and child labour. Yet the exploitation may draw complicity from the labourer whose terms of contract resemble those of co-existing and pre-existing attached labour relationships in the region. We would argue that in addition to being exploitative and parasitic on the hard work of labourers, the intermediaries are also using traditional caste-based and patriarchal modes of oppression to maintain their exploitative labour relations.
Underneath the actions of the agents involved, we also have to look at the roles and identities that are internalised by workers. Maistries and group maistries are seen as those who save the labourer in distress by offering work when otherwise they might starve. Some lower-caste people who serve the landlords and employers think they will be rewarded with patronage during crises. This patronage may at present consist only of loans which further bind the worker and the worker’s family. It would be misleading to judge from some workers’ attitudes such as loyalty, dependence, devotion and submission that their bondage is completely self-chosen and voluntary. On the contrary, studying local cases of resistance, resentment, and revolt would throw more light on the underlying compulsions as shown by Kapadia (1995) and by Lerche (1995). This is an area for future research.
Organising labour in the light of the informal and interlocked nature of labour markets poses an extremely difficult task. Migrant labourers are scattered and often travelling. The eradication of bonded labour will need a multi-pronged strategy involving propaganda, legislation, mobilisation, rehabilitation, and some provision of basic amenities. Any fragmented effort may fail. Isolated attempts to rehabilitate people have been failures. Low wages, both for men and for women, themselves have to come under scrutiny, since the lack of independent subsistence is one reason why people accept bondage. The state has tried three means to help such workers: the minimum wage laws, which are hardly ever implemented where local market wages lie below them; the employment guarantee programmes, which have not been enough to meet the needs of the masses; and the law abolishing bonded labour (dated 1976) which is still not effective. A new strategy is needed.
The NGOs in the district have started women's education
programmes which try to empower people to secure access to specific government
relief programmes. In particular, women are taught to approach authorities
directly for seeking access to local employment schemes. Our analysis has
shown that the oppression that is linked to value-exploitation extends into
family life, village rituals, traditions and norms of caste hierarchy, and thus
is to some extent beyond the reach of the modern state. The elimination of
the parasitic middlemen’s role is part of the answer yet more fundamental
changes are also needed. In the process of struggle, any measures taken
must recognise the past structural locations, the beliefs and values, and the
embodied capabilities of workers, as well as the dyadic long-term relationships
upon which some workers depend. Nevertheless, there are prospects for
change:
Notes
1. We are grateful for comments received at the Conference of the Indian Political Economy Association, 1995, and at the Conference of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics, 1994, on material presented here. We also wish to thank D. Narasimha Reddy for his support regarding this work. Finally, we are grateful to the advice of the anonymous reviewers regarding revision of the paper. back to text
2. "Manu, writing later than Koutilya, outlined only seven categories of dasas. They are: persons captured in battle; those enslaved in return for food; dasas born in the house of the master; those who are bought; dasas inherited as part of patrimony; dasas who are given away by their parents; and persons enslaved for not paying a fine." See Chakravarthy (1985), 40. back to text
3. An account of various colonial laws is given by Dingwaney (1985) in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985), 340-50. back to text
4. One example illustrating the gender bias implicit in
ungendered analyses of ‘workers’ is van der Linden’s analysis of
employers’ and employees’ strategic choices regarding employment relations.
Van der Linden glosses over gender differences and possible additional sources
of control or oppression facing women, relative to men. Van der Linden
presents an idealised model of employers’ motives and employees’ motives.
His use of s/he as the pronoun for employers here does not resolve the problem
of having a fundamentally ungendered analysis at this point (1998: 516-519).
back to text
5. Studies such as Kapadia (1995) and Lerche (1995) diverge from the pattern set by Bhaduri (1983) and Miles (1987). back to text
6. Mahabubnagar was earlier known as Palamuuru. It was renamed after the erstwhile ruler, the 6th Nizam, Mir Mahabubali Khan in 1929, but people still call it informally by its old name, and the migrant labourers are referred to as Palamuuru labour. The district was under autonomous kingdoms (Samsthanams), and administratively and politically the region remained isolated and insulated from the famous Telangana Peasant armed revolt of 1947. back to text
7. The Report on Indebtedness
in Nizam Domain (1934) mentioned that the district was under severe drought,
near famine conditions, with loss of cattle and subsequent indebtedness among
farmers.
back to text
8. "The construction of Nizamsagar dam involved a massive need for labour both skilled and unskilled. Especially excavation of earth, blasting, blasting rock in foundation, quarrying stone for machinery and miscellaneous. The labour for these works had been imported from dominions including Raichur, Gulbarga, Mahabubnagar, Nalgonda and Karimnagar...Palmuuries coming from Mahabubnagar did a good work at excavation, especially earth work at ground level...The method of recruiting the labourers is mainly through the department by forwarding advances ranging from Rs. 5 to Rs. 10 per year for the gangs willing to come." The Report on the History of Nizamsagar Project, Hyderabad, Deccan, Public works Dept., H.E.H.Nizam Dominion, 1939 (A.P.Archives, Hyderabad). back to text
9. The use of the male gender here is important empirically because (a) one cannot study female supervisors, so can only comment on male supervisors; and (b) the gendering of supervision may give hints to future researchers on why the system perpetuates itself so repeatedly. Life histories, family case studies, or critical incident analysis may be needed to examine why men turn to this particular activity and how these men interact with the large contractors in ways that ultimately exploit both men and women. The present study has more limited aims and did not use in-depth qualitative methods. back to text
10. At the rate of 4 hours per day of extra-labour, there are 112 days of unpaid work! Taking 336 workdays per year multiplied by Rs. 35 daily wage (Hyderabad construction industry wage at that time) the sum is Rs. 11,820. Assuming an absence of 30 days in that period, the labourer is still entitled to Rs. 10,710. back to text
11. The public works
department while calling for tenders on construction work gives a rough cost of
production, which includes provision of market wages. The lowest bidder is
given the contract and there is nobody to check on what is actually paid.
The construction companies find it advantageous to rely on the middlemen for
various reasons such as easy mobilisation and few direct management
problems—it’s the maestry’s headache and the company can save a phenomenal
amount of money by underpayment. The labour supply is not only assured for
the present but also for the future.
back to text
12. By contrast the statutory minimum wages for agricultural labour tasks over this period were all less than Rs. 20 per day. back to text
13. According to the Bonded Labour Abolition Act, a person is presumed to have entered into the contract in consideration of i) advance of money by the person/ascendants/descendants from the employer, or ii) in consideration of being born a certain caste, or...for a specified/unspecified period of time, based on oral or written contract. Bonded Labour Abolition Act 1976, Labour Year Book, Labour Bureau. Shimla. 1-5. See also Brass (1997b: 42) for a review of what he calls India’s ‘law-as-rhetoric’. back to text
14. From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
15. Given the subsistence nature of the local agriculture, these gross farm incomes had to be estimated from information on the yield and acreage of respondents’ fields, after deducting the imputed cost of reported purchased inputs. Net incomes were also calculated by deducting imputed values of family labour, using an estimated 1991 local wage rate of Rs. 10 per day for all. Actual wages vary according to the sex and age of worker, and by task, but this minimal figure was used as a rough estimate’. back to text
16. In Telugu the word for famine also means drought (karuvu). back to text
17. From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
18. From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
19. From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
20. From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
21. From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
22. From field data collected
by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994. back to text
Sources
Agarwal, Bina. (1998).
"Disinherited Peasants, Disadvantaged Workers: A Gender Perspective on Land
and Livelihood," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. Vol.
33, No. 13. A2-A28.
back to text
Bagchi, A.K. (1975). "Relation of Agriculture to Industry in the Context of South Asia," in Frontier. Autumn. 22-24.
Balagopal, K. (1988). Probings in the Political Economy of Agrarian Classes and Conflicts. Hyderabad: Perspectives Press. back to text
Bandyopadyaya. (1976). "Vettichakiri in M.K.," in National Labour Institute Bulletin. No. 2 (3).
Bardhan, P. K., ed. (1989). The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Barucha, S.M. (1937). Agricultural Indebtedness in H.E.H. Nizam Dominion. Hyderabad: Andhra Pradesh Archives.
Basu, Kaushik. (1983). "The Emergence of Isolation and Interlinkage in Rural Markets," Oxford Economic Papers. No. 35. 262-280. back to text
Basu, Kaushik. (1986). "One
Kind of Power," Oxford Economic Papers. No. 38. 259-282.
back to text
Bhaduri, Amit. (1973). "A Study in Agricultural Backwardness Under Semi-Feudalism," in Economic Journal. March. 120-37. back to text
Bhaduri, Amit. (1983). The
Economic Structure of Backward Agriculture. Delhi: Macmillan.
back to text
Bhaduri, Amit. (1986). "Forced Commerce and Agrarian Growth," in World Development. 14:2. 267-272.
Bhaduri, A. (1977). "On the Formation of Usurious Interest Rates in Backward Agriculture," in Cambridge Journal of Economics. No. 1. 341-352. back to text
Bhalla, A.S., et al, eds. (1993). Images of Rural India in Twentieth Century. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Bharadwaj, Krishna. (1985). "A View on Commercialisation in Indian Agriculture and Development of Capitalism," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 12, No. 4. 494-519. back to text
Bharadwaj, Krishna, and P.K. Das. (1975). "Tenurial Conditions and Modes of Exploitation," in Economic and Political Weekly. June. Vol. 10. A49-55.
Brass, Tom. (1986). "The Elementary Strictures of Kinship: Unfree Relations and the Production of Commodities," in Social Analysis. No. 20. back to text
Brass, Tom. (1990). "Class Struggle and Deproletarianisation of Agricultural Labour in Haryana (India)," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 18, No. 1. 36-67. back to text
Brass, Tom. (1991). "Market Essentialism and the Impermissibility of Unfree Labour: A Reply to Shlomowitz," in Slavery and Abolition. Vol. 12, No. 3. 225-244.
Brass, Tom. (1995). "Unfree Labour and Agrarian Change: A Different View," in Economic and Political Weekly. 1 April. 697-699. back to text
Brass, Tom. (1997a). "Some Observations on Unfree Labour, Capitalist Restructuring and Deproletarianisation," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). 57-76. back to text
Brass, Tom. (1997b). "Introduction," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). 11-44. back to text
Brass, Tom, and Henry Bernstein. (1992). "Introduction: Proletarianisation and Deproletarianisation on the Colonial Plantations," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 19. 1-40. back to text
Brass, Tom, and Marcel van der Linden, eds. (1998). Free and Unfree Labour: The Debate Continues. Berlin and Paris: Peter Lang AG. back to text
Breman, Jan. (1984). Of Peasants, Paupers and Migrants. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Chakravarty, U. (1985). "Of Dasas and Karmakaras: Servile Labour in Ancient India," in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985). 35-75 back to text
Dingwaney, Manjari. (1985). "Unredeemed Promises: The Law and Servitude," in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985). 283-347.
Fay, Brian. (1987). Critical Social Science: Liberation and its Limits. Oxford: Polity. back to text
Government of Andhra Pradesh, Bureau of Economics and Statistics (various years). Handbook of Statistics, Mahabuubnagar District, Hyderabad. back to text
Grossman, Jonathan. (1998). "The Right to Strike and Worker Freedom in and beyond Apartheid," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). back to text
Harriss, J. (1982). Capitalism and Peasant Farming: Agrarian Structure and Ideology in Northern Tamil Nadu. Bombay. back to text
Harriss-White, B. (1996). A Political Economy of Agricultural Markets in South India: Masters of the Countryside. New Delhi: Sage. back to text
H.E.H. Nizam Dominion. (1939). The Report on the History of Nizamsagar Project. Hyderabad, Deccan, Public Works Department. (Andhra Pradesh Archives, Hyderabad). back to text
Himmelweit, S. (1995). "The Discovery of ‘Unpaid Work’: The Social Consequences of the Expansion of ‘Work’," in Feminist Economics. Vol. 1, No. 2. 1-20. back to text
Hjejle, Benedicte. (1967). "Slavery and Agricultural Bondage in South India in the Nineteenth Century," in Scandinavian Economic History Review. Vol. XI, Nos. 1-2. back to text
Hodgson, Geoffrey. (1982). Capitalism,
Value and Exploitation. London: Martin Robertson.
back to text
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1989). "Institutional Economic Theory: the Old Versus the New," in Review of Political Economy. Vol. 1, No. 3. 249-269.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1993). "Institutional Economics: Surveying the 'Old' and the 'New'," in Economics and Evolution: Bringing Life Back into Economics. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press. Originally published in Metroeconomica. Vol. 44, No. 1, 1993. 1-28. back to text
Hoff, K. and J. Stiglitz. (1990). "Imperfect Information and Rural Credit Markets: Puzzles and Policy Perspectives," in World Bank Economic Review. Vol. 4, No. 3. 235-250. back to text
Jodhka, Surinder Singh.
(1994). "Agrarian Change and Attached Labour: Emerging Patterns in Haryana
Agriculture," in Economic and Political Weekly. 24 September. Vol.
29, No. 39.
back to text
Kabeer, N. (1994). Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought. London: Verso, and Delhi: Kali for Women. back to text
Kalpagam, U. (1994). Labour & Gender: Survival in Urban India. Delhi: Sage. back to text
Kapadia, Karen. (1992). "Every Blade of Green: Landless Women Labourers, Production and Reproduction in South India," in Indian Journal of Labour Economics. 35:3. 266-276. back to text
Kapadia, Karen. (1995). "The Profitability of Bonded Labour: The Gem-Cutting Industry in Rural South India," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 22:3, April. 446-483. back to text
Kerr, Ian J. (1998). "Free or Unfree? Railway Construction Labour in Nineteenth Century India," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). back to text
Kosambi.D.D. (1956). "On the Development of Feudalism in India," in Journal of Bombay Branch of Royal Asiatic Society. 31/32. 258-69. back to text
Krishnaiah, M. (1998). "Regular Farm Labour System in Semi-Arid Areas: Emerging Patterns in Andhra Pradesh," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. A20-A28.
Kulke, Hermann, ed. (1997). The State in India 1000-1700. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Kumar, Dharma. (1967). Labour and Caste in South India: Agriculture in Madras Presidency. London: Cambridge University Press.
Labour Bureau. "Bonded Labour Abolition Act 1976," in Labour Year Book. Shimla. 1-5.
Lerche, Jens. (1998). "Agricultural Labourers, the State and Agrarian Transition in Uttar Pradesh," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. A29-A35. back to text
Lerche, Jens. (1995). "Is Bonded Labour a Bound Category? Reconceptualising Agrarian Conflict in India," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 22:3, April. 484-515. back to text
Miles, Robert. (1987). Capitalism and Unfree Labour: Anomaly or Necessity?. London: Tavistock. back to text
Mohan Rao, J. (1999). "Agrarian Power and Unfree Labour," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 26: 2/3. 242-262.
Olsen, Wendy K. (1996). "Marxist and Neo-Classical Approaches to Unfree Labour in India," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). 379-404. back to text
Olsen, Wendy K. (1998). "Paradigms in the Analysis of Credit Structures and Discourses in South Indian Banking," Working Paper No. 5, September. University of Bradford, Graduate School of Social Sciences and Humanities. back to text
Patnaik, Utsa. (1983). Peasant Differetiation. New Delhi: Oxford University Press. back to text
Patnaik, Utsa, and Manjari Dingwaney, eds. (1985). Chains of Servitude: Bondage and Slavery In India. New Delhi: Sangam Publishing. back to text
Pradan, H.Pradhan. (1979). "Semi-feudalism: The Basic Constraints of Indian Agriculture," in Arvind N. Das and V. Nilkanth, eds. Agrarian Relations in India. New Delhi.
Prakash, Gyan. (1990). Bonded Histories: Genealogies of Labor Servitude in Colonial India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. back to text
Radhakrishna, R., et al. (1987). "A Study of Poverty Levels: Inter-District Analysis," Working Paper No. 431. Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad. back to text
Ramachandran, V.K. (1990). Wage Labour and Unfreedom: An Indian Case Study. Oxford: Oxford University Press. back to text
Ramana Murthy, R. V. (1991).
"Seasonal Labour Migration In Semi-Arid Areas: A Case Study of Palamuuru
Labour," M.Phil. thesis, Department of Economics, University of Hyderabad.
back to text
Rammohan, C. (1987). Palamuuru Labour (Telugu). Hyderabad: VIRASAM (Revolutionary Writers Association).
Rao, R.S. (1995). Towards Understanding Semi-Feudal Semi-Colonial Society. Hyderabad: Perspectives Press. Series title: D. Narasimha Reddy, ed. Studies in Political Economy. Department of Economics, University of Hyderabad. back to text
Rao, Usha. (1994). Palamoor Labour: A Study of Migrant Labour in Mahabubnagar District. C.D. Deshmukh Impact Centre, Council For Social Development, Hyderabad. back to text
Ravinder, A. (1989). "Labour Migration: A Dimension of Poverty," unpublished M.Phil. thesis, Department of Economics, Osmania University, Hyderabad. back to text
Reddy, D. Narasimha. (1990). Rural Migrant Labour in Andhra Pradesh. Report submitted to the National Commission on Rural Labour, Government of India. back to text
Saradamoni, Kunjuleks. (1973). "Agrestic Servitude in Kerala in the Nineteenth Century Century," in Indian Economic and Social History Review. 371-385. back to text
Saradamoni, Kunjuleks. (1980). Emergence of a Slave Caste: The Pulayyas of Kerala. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House. back to text
Sarkar, T. (1985). "Bondage In Colonial Context," in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985). 97-126. back to text
Sharma, R.S. (1956). "The Origins of Feudalism in India (c.AD 400-650)," in JESHO. 1. 297-328.
Sinha, Shantha. (1993). "Changing Landlord-Labour Relationships," in Bhalla, A.S., et al, eds. (1993).
Srinivasan, T.N. (1989). "On Choice Among Creditors and Bonded Labour Contracts," in P. K. Bardhan, ed. (1989). 203-220. back to text
Srivastava, Ravi. (1989). "Interlinked Modes of Exploitation in Indian Agriculture During Transition: A Case Study," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 16, No. 4. 493-522. back to text
Standing, Guy. (1981). "Migration and Modes of Exploitation: Social Origins of Immobility and Mobility," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 8, No. 2. 173-211.
Stein, Burton. (1980). Peasant State and Society in Medieval in South India. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Subrahmaniam, Rama Raju, and Thimma Reddy. (1994). Bonded Labour in Andhra Pradesh (A Study in Medak District). Hyderabad: Centre for Economic and Social Studies. back to text
Thapar, Romila. (1960). A History of India - Vol. 1. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Thompson, E.P. (1978). The Poverty of Theory and Other Essays. London: Merlin. back to text
Unni, Jeemol. (1998). "Non-Agricultural Employment and Poverty in Rural India: A Review of Evidence," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. A36-A44.
Venkateswarlu, D. (1997). Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Hyderabad. back to text
Walker, T.S., and J.G. Ryan. (1990). Village and Household Economies in India's Semi-arid Tropics. Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press. back to text